lattice model (finance)

 

  • Given this functional link to volatility, note now the resultant difference in the construction relative to equity implied trees: for interest rates, the volatility is known
    for each time-step, and the node-values (i.e.

  • Option valuation then proceeds as standard, with these substituted for p. For DKC, the first step is to recover the state prices corresponding to each node in the tree, such
    that these are consistent with observed option prices (i.e.

  • [39] An alternate approach, originally published by Goldman Sachs (1994),[40] does not decouple the components, rather, discounting is at a conversion-probability-weighted
    risk-free and risky interest rate within a single tree.

  • The first step is to trace the evolution of the option’s key underlying variable(s), starting with today’s spot price, such that this process is consistent with its volatility;
    log-normal Brownian motion with constant volatility is usually assumed.

  • In the latter case, the calibration is directly on the lattice: the fit is to both the current term structure of interest rates (i.e.

  • interest rates) must be solved for specified risk neutral probabilities; for equity, on the other hand, a single volatility cannot be specified per time-step, i.e.

  • The second step is to then incorporate any term structure of volatility by building a corresponding DKC tree (based on every second time-step in the CRR tree: as DKC is trinomial
    whereas CRR is binomial) and then using this for option valuation.

  • For rho, sensitivity to interest rates, and vega, sensitivity to input volatility, the measurement is indirect, as the value must be calculated a second time on a new lattice
    built with these inputs slightly altered – and the sensitivity here is likewise returned via finite difference.

  • [31] In the former case, the approach is to “calibrate” the model parameters, such that bond prices produced by the model, in its continuous form, best fit observed market
    prices.

  • [4] The next step is to value the option recursively: stepping backwards from the final time-step, where we have exercise value at each node; and applying risk neutral valuation
    at each earlier node, where option value is the probability-weighted present value of the up- and down-nodes in the later time-step.

  • price, are approximated given differences between option prices – with their related spot – in the same time step.

  • For caps (and floors) step 1 and 2 are combined: at each node the value is based on the relevant nodes at the later step, plus, for any caplet (floorlet) maturing in the time-step,
    the difference between its reference-rate and the short-rate at the node (and reflecting the corresponding day count fraction and notional-value exchanged).

  • Thereafter the up-, down- and middle-probabilities are found for each node such that: these sum to 1; spot prices adjacent time-step-wise evolve risk neutrally, incorporating
    dividend yield; state prices similarly “grow” at the risk free rate.

  • For interest rate derivatives lattices are additionally useful in that they address many of the issues encountered with continuous models, such as pull to par.

  • For a bond with an embedded option, the standard yield to maturity based calculations of duration and convexity do not consider how changes in interest rates will alter the
    cash flows due to option exercise.

  • Interest rate derivatives Lattices are commonly used in valuing bond options, swaptions, and other interest rate derivatives[23][24] In these cases the valuation is largely
    as above, but requires an additional, zeroeth, step of constructing an interest rate tree, on which the price of the underlying is then based.

  • As stated above, the lattice approach is particularly useful in valuing American options, where the choice whether to exercise the option early, or to hold the option, may
    be modeled at each discrete time/price combination; this is also true for Bermudan options.

  • [4] In the limit, as the number of time-steps increases, these converge to the Log-normal distribution, and hence produce the “same” option price as Black-Scholes: to achieve
    this, these will variously seek to agree with the underlying’s central moments, raw moments and / or log-moments at each time-step, as measured discretely.

  • For similar reasons, real options and employee stock options are often modeled using a lattice framework, though with modified assumptions.

  • Since the 2007–2012 global financial crisis, swap pricing is (generally) under a “multi-curve framework”, whereas previously it was off a single, “self discounting”, curve;
    see Interest rate swap § Valuation and pricing.

  • Here, the share price may remain unchanged over the time-step, and option valuation is then based on the value of the share at the up-, down- and middle-nodes in the later
    time-step.

  • [26] The approach for bond options is described aside—note that this approach addresses the problem of pull to par experienced under closed form approaches; see Black–Scholes
    model § Valuing bond options.

  • The trinomial model is considered[12] to produce more accurate results than the binomial model when fewer time steps are modelled, and is therefore used when computational
    speed or resources may be an issue.

  • The former is easier built, but is consistent with one maturity only; the latter will be consistent with, but at the same time requires, known (or interpolated) prices at
    all time-steps and nodes.

  • For callable- and putable bonds a third step would be required: at each node in the time-step incorporate the effect of the embedded option on the bond price and / or the
    option price there before stepping-backwards one time-step.

  • [14] Using the calibrated lattice one can then price options with strike / maturity combinations not quoted in the market, such that these prices are consistent with observed
    volatility patterns.

  • For vanilla options, as the number of steps increases, the results rapidly converge, and the binomial model is then preferred due to its simpler implementation.

  • A continuous model, on the other hand, such as Black–Scholes, would only allow for the valuation of European options, where exercise is on the option’s maturity date.

  • [35] With the zeroeth step thus accomplished, the valuation will proceed largely as previously, using steps 1 and onwards, but here with cashflows based on the LIBOR “dimension”,
    and discounting using the corresponding nodes from the OIS “dimension”.

  • For equity options, a typical example would be pricing an American option, where a decision as to option exercise is required at “all” times (any time) before and including
    maturity.

  • Here, similar to rho and vega above, the interest rate tree is rebuilt for an upward and then downward parallel shift in the yield curve and these measures are calculated
    numerically given the corresponding changes in bond value.

  • The next step also differs: the underlying price here is built via “backward induction” i.e.

  • Theta, sensitivity to time, is likewise estimated given the option price at the first node in the tree and the option price for the same spot in a later time step.

  • These trees thus “ensure that all European standard options (with strikes and maturities coinciding with the tree nodes) will have theoretical values which match their market
    prices”.

  • [2] The method is also used for valuing certain exotic options, where because of path dependence in the payoff, Monte Carlo methods for option pricing fail to account for
    optimal decisions to terminate the derivative by early exercise,[3] though methods now exist for solving this problem.

  • An alternative approach to modeling (American) bond options, particularly those struck on yield to maturity (YTM), employs modified equity-lattice methods.

  • Here, calibration means that the interest-rate-tree reproduces the prices of the zero-coupon bonds—and any other interest-rate sensitive securities—used in constructing the
    yield curve; note the parallel to the implied trees for equity above, and compare Bootstrapping (finance).

  • of the rates applicable historically for the time-step; to be market-consistent, analysts generally prefer to use current interest rate cap prices, and the implied volatility
    for the Black-76-prices of each component caplet; see Interest rate cap § Implied Volatilities.)

  • As regards the construction, for an R-IBT the first step is to recover the “Implied Ending Risk-Neutral Probabilities” of spot prices.

 

Works Cited

[‘1. Staff, Investopedia (17 November 2010). “Lattice-Based Model”.
2. ^ Hull, J. C. (2006). Options, futures, and other derivatives. Pearson Education India.
3. ^ Cox, J. C., Ross, S. A., & Rubinstein, M. (1979). Option pricing: A simplified approach.
Journal of financial Economics, 7(3), 229–263.
4. ^ Jump up to:a b Chance, Don M. March 2008 A Synthesis of Binomial Option Pricing Models for Lognormally Distributed Assets Archived 2016-03-04 at the Wayback Machine. Journal of Applied Finance,
Vol. 18
5. ^ Timothy Klassen. (2001) Simple, Fast and Flexible Pricing of Asian Options, Journal of Computational Finance, 4 (3) 89-124 (2001)
6. ^ John Hull and Alan White. (1993) Efficient procedures for valuing European and American path-dependent
options, Journal of Derivatives, Fall, 21-31
7. ^ Ronnie Becker. (N.D.). Pricing in the Binomial Model, African Institute for Mathematical Sciences
8. ^ Prof. Markus K. Brunnermeier. Multi-period Model Options, Princeton University.
9. ^ Jump
up to:a b Mark s. Joshi (2008). The Convergence of Binomial Trees for Pricing the American Put Archived 2015-07-02 at the Wayback Machine
10. ^ Mark Rubinstein (2000). On the Relation Between Binomial and Trinomial Option Pricing Models. The Journal
of Derivatives, Winter 2000, 8 (2) 47-50
11. ^ Zaboronski et al (2010). Pricing Options Using Trinomial Trees. University of Warwick
12. ^ “Option Pricing & Stock Price Probability Calculators – Hoadley”. www.hoadley.net.
13. ^ Don Chance. (2010)
Calculating the Greeks in the Binomial Model.
14. ^ Jump up to:a b Emanuel Derman, Iraj Kani, and Neil Chriss (1996). Implied Trinomial Trees of the Volatility Smile. Goldman Sachs, Quantitative Strategies Research Notes
15. ^ Mark Rubinstein
(1994). Implied Binomial Trees. Journal of Finance. July, 1994.
16. ^ Emanuel Derman and Iraj Kani (1994). The Volatility Smile and Its Implied Tree. Research Note, Goldman Sachs.
17. ^ Jim Clark, Les Clewlow and Chris Strickland (2008). Calibrating
trees to the market prices of options. Energy Risk, August 2008. (Archived, 2015-06-30)
18. ^ Mark Rubinstein (1998). Edgeworth Binomial Trees. Journal of Derivatives, Spring 1998.
19. ^ “Wiley: Advanced Modelling in Finance using Excel and VBA
– Mary Jackson, Mike Staunton”. eu.wiley.com.
20. ^ Jean-Guy Simonato (2011). Johnson binomial trees, Quantitative Finance, Volume 11, Pages 1165-1176
21. ^ Mark Rubinstein (January 15, 1995). “Rainbow Options”. Archived from the original on 22
June 2007.
22. ^ Isabel Ehrlich (2012). Pricing Basket Options with Smile. Thesis, Imperial College
23. ^ Martin Haugh (2010). Term Structure Lattice Models, Columbia University
24. ^ S. Benninga and Z. Wiener. (1998).Binomial Term Structure
Models, Mathematica in Education and Research. Vol.7 No.3
25. ^ M. Leippold and Z. Wiener (2003). Efficient Calibration of Trinomial Trees for One-Factor Short Rate Models
26. ^ Jump up to:a b c Pricing Interest Rate-dependent Financial Claims
with Option Features, Ch 11. in Rendleman (2002), per Bibliography.
27. ^ Prof. Don Chance, Louisiana State University. The Heath-Jarrow-Morton Term Structure Model Archived 2015-09-23 at the Wayback Machine
28. ^ Grant, Dwight M.; Vora, Gautam
(26 February 2009). “Implementing No-Arbitrage Term Structure of Interest Rate Models in Discrete Time When Interest Rates Are Normally Distributed”. The Journal of Fixed Income. 8 (4): 85–98. doi:10.3905/jfi.1999.319247. S2CID 153599970.
29. ^
Rubinstein, Mark (1 January 1999). Rubinstein on Derivatives. Risk Books. ISBN 9781899332533 – via Google Books.
30. ^ S. Derrick, D. Stapleton and R. Stapleton (2005). The Libor Market Model: A Recombining Binomial Tree Methodology
31. ^ Dr.
Graeme West (2010). Interest Rate Derivatives
32. ^ “Calibrating the Ornstein-Uhlenbeck (Vasicek) model”. www.sitmo.com. Archived from the original on 2015-06-19. Retrieved 2015-06-19.
33. ^ “embedded option, thefreedictionary.com”.
34. ^ Riskworx
(c. 2000). American Bond Option Pricing, riskworx.com
35. ^ John Hull and Alan White (2015). Multi-Curve Modeling Using Trees
36. ^ “Pricing Convertible Bonds”.
37. ^ Tsiveriotis and Fernandes (1998). “Valuing Convertible Bonds with Credit Risk”,
Journal of Fixed Income.
38. ^ Kurt Hess. “Description of Tree Model for the Valuation of a Convertible Bond with Credit Risk”. University of Waikato. Archived from the original on 2012-03-21. Retrieved 2015-06-12.
39. ^ D. R. Chambers, Qin Lu.
“A Tree Model for Pricing Convertible Bonds with Equity, Interest Rate, and Default Risk” (PDF). Journal of Derivatives. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2016-04-21. Retrieved 31 May 2007.
40. ^ Goldman Sachs (1994). Valuing Convertible Bonds
as Derivatives
41. ^ Aswath Damodaran (2002). Valuing Firms in Distress
42. ^ Grant Thornton (2013). “Valuation Considerations Related to Complex Financial Instruments for Investment Companies” (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2015-07-09.
Retrieved 2015-07-08.
43. ^ “Not Found – Business Valuation Resources” (PDF). www.bvresources.com.
44. ^ Aswath Damodaran. Option Pricing Applications in Valuation
45. ^ Mark Broadie and Ozgur Kaya (2007). A Binomial Lattice Method for Pricing
Corporate Debt and Modeling Chapter 11 Proceedings, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 42, No. 2
46. ^ See Fabozzi under Bibliography.
Photo credit: https://www.flickr.com/photos/18_2rosadik36/7551637034/’]