price elasticity of demand

 

  • First, a good’s elasticity is not necessarily constant; it varies at different points along the demand curve because a 1% change in price has a quantity effect that may depend
    on whether the initial price is high or low.

  • [8][9] If a 1% rise in the price of gasoline causes a 0.5% fall in the quantity of cars demanded, the cross-price elasticity is As the size of the price change gets bigger,
    the elasticity definition becomes less reliable for a combination of two reasons.

  • Demand for a good is said to be inelastic when the elasticity is less than one in absolute value: that is, changes in price have a relatively small effect on the quantity
    demanded.

  • As a result, the relationship between elasticity and revenue can be described for any good:[38][39] • When the price elasticity of demand for a good is perfectly inelastic,
    changes in the price do not affect the quantity demanded for the good; raising prices will always cause total revenue to increase.

  • • When the price elasticity of demand is perfectly elastic, any increase in the price, no matter how small, will cause the quantity demanded for the good to drop to zero.

  • [17][19] Point elasticity[edit] The point elasticity of demand method is used to determine change in demand within the same demand curve, basically a very small amount of
    change in demand is measured through point elasticity.

  • He described price elasticity of demand as thus: “And we may say generally:— the elasticity (or responsiveness) of demand in a market is great or small according as the amount
    demanded increases much or little for a given fall in price, and diminishes much or little for a given rise in price”.

  • [7] Since the price elasticity of demand is negative for the vast majority of goods and services (unlike most other elasticities, which take both positive and negative values
    depending on the good), economists often leave off the word “negative” or the minus sign and refer to the price elasticity of demand as a positive value (i.e., in absolute value terms).

  • For example, when demand is perfectly inelastic, by definition consumers have no alternative to purchasing the good or service if the price increases, so the quantity demanded
    would remain constant.

  • Two important special cases are perfectly elastic demand (= ∞), where even a small rise in price reduces the quantity demanded to zero; and perfectly inelastic demand (= 0),
    where a rise in price leaves the quantity unchanged.

  • A good with an elasticity of −2 has elastic demand because quantity demanded falls twice as much as the price increase; an elasticity of −0.5 has inelastic demand because
    the change in quantity demanded change is half of the price increase.

  • In terms of partial-differential calculus, point elasticity of demand can be defined as follows:[22] let be the demand of goods as a function of parameters price and wealth,
    and let be the demand for good .

  • [33] When the goods represent only a negligible portion of the budget the income effect will be insignificant and demand inelastic,[33] Necessity The more necessary a good
    is, the lower the elasticity, as people will attempt to buy it no matter the price, such as the case of insulin for those who need it.

  • In other words, we can say that the price elasticity of demand is the percentage change in demand for a commodity due to a given percentage change in the price.

  • [13][29] Duration For most goods, the longer a price change holds, the higher the elasticity is likely to be, as more and more consumers find they have the time and inclination
    to search for substitutes.

  • For inelastic goods, because of the inverse nature of the relationship between price and quantity demanded (i.e., the law of demand), the two effects affect total revenue
    in opposite directions.

  • The price elasticity gives the percentage change in quantity demanded when there is a one percent increase in price, holding everything else constant.

  • [27] A number of factors can thus affect the elasticity of demand for a good:[28] Availability of substitute goods The more and closer the substitutes available, the higher
    the elasticity is likely to be, as people can easily switch from one good to another if an even minor price change is made;[28][29][30] There is a strong substitution effect.

  • • When the price elasticity of demand is unit (or unitary) elastic, the percentage change in quantity demanded is equal to that in price, so a change in price will not affect
    total revenue.

  • Revenue is simply the product of unit price times quantity: Generally, any change in price will have two effects:[36] The price effect For inelastic goods, an increase in
    unit price will tend to increase revenue, while a decrease in price will tend to decrease revenue.

  • The fundamental equation for one product becomes and the corresponding equation for several products becomes Excel models are available that compute constant elasticity, and
    use non-constant elasticity to estimate prices that optimize revenue or profit for one product[41] or several products.

  • [3] The formula for the coefficient of price elasticity of demand for a good is:[4][5][6] where is the initial price of the good demanded, is how much it changed, is the initial
    quantity of the good demanded, and is how much it changed.

  • In the opposite case, when demand is perfectly elastic, by definition consumers have an infinite ability to switch to alternatives if the price increases, so they would stop
    buying the good or service in question completely—quantity demanded would fall to zero.

  • For example, Company X’s fish and chips would tend to have a relatively high elasticity of demand if a significant number of substitutes are available, whereas food in general
    would have an extremely low elasticity of demand because no substitutes exist.

  • This form of the equations shows that point elasticities assumed constant over a price range cannot determine what prices generate maximum values of ; similarly they cannot
    predict prices that generate maximum or maximum revenue.

  • • When the price elasticity of demand is relatively elastic, the percentage change in quantity demanded is greater than that in price.

  • It may also be defined as the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded to the percentage change in price of particular commodity.

  • [39] It is important to realize that price-elasticity of demand is not necessarily constant over all price ranges.

  • Constant elasticity and optimal pricing[edit] If one point elasticity is used to model demand changes over a finite range of prices, elasticity is implicitly assumed constant
    with respect to price over the finite price range.

  • Arc Elasticity is a second solution to the asymmetry problem of having an elasticity dependent on which of the two given points on a demand curve is chosen as the “original”
    point will and which as the “new” one is to compute the percentage change in P and Q relative to the average of the two prices and the average of the two quantities, rather than just the change relative to one point or the other.

  • The above measure of elasticity is sometimes referred to as the own-price elasticity of demand for a good, i.e., the elasticity of demand with respect to the good’s own price,
    in order to distinguish it from the elasticity of demand for that good with respect to the change in the price of some other good, i.e., an independent, complementary, or substitute good.

  • [2] At an elasticity of 0 consumption would not change at all, in spite of any price increases.

  • Effect on tax incidence Demand elasticity, in combination with the price elasticity of supply can be used to assess where the incidence (or “burden”) of a per-unit tax is
    falling or to predict where it will fall if the tax is imposed.

  • [3] That two-good type of elasticity is called a cross-price elasticity of demand.

  • Non-constant elasticity and optimal pricing[edit] If the definition of price elasticity is extended to yield a quadratic relationship between demand units and price, then
    it is possible to compute prices that maximize , , and revenue.

  • • When the price elasticity of demand is relatively inelastic , the percentage change in quantity demanded is smaller than that in price.

  • He used Cournot’s basic creating of the demand curve to get the equation for price elasticity of demand.

  • )[37] The percentage change in quantity is related to the percentage change in price by elasticity: hence the percentage change in revenue can be calculated by knowing the
    elasticity and the percentage change in price alone.

  • If demand is inelastic, the good’s demand is relatively insensitive to price, with quantity changing less than price.

  • Definition The variation in demand in response to a variation in price is called price elasticity of demand.

  • The price elasticity of demand is ordinarily negative because quantity demanded falls when price rises, as described by the “law of demand”.

  • [35] Effect on entire revenue A firm considering a price change must know what effect the change in price will have on total revenue.

  • This is the approach taken in the definition of point elasticity, which uses differential calculus to calculate the elasticity for an infinitesimal change in price and quantity
    at any given point on the demand curve:[20] In other words, it is equal to the absolute value of the first derivative of quantity with respect to price multiplied by the point’s price (P) divided by its quantity (Qd).

  • But in determining whether to increase or decrease prices, a firm needs to know what the net effect will be.

  • This is a price increase of 60% and a quantity decline of 20%, an elasticity of for that part of the demand curve.

  • As a result, this measure is known as the arc elasticity, in this case with respect to the price of the good.

  • If the price falls from $16 to $10 and the quantity rises from 80 units to 100, however, the price decline is 37.5% and the quantity gain is 25%, an elasticity of for the
    same part of the curve.

  • Hence, as the accompanying diagram shows, total revenue is maximized at the combination of price and quantity demanded where the elasticity of demand is unitary.

  • Hence, suppliers can increase the price by the full amount of the tax, and the consumer would end up paying the entirety.

  • One way to avoid the accuracy problem described above is to minimize the difference between the starting and ending prices and quantities.

  • The linear demand curve in the accompanying diagram illustrates that changes in price also change the elasticity: the price elasticity is different at every point on the curve.

 

Works Cited

[‘”Price elasticity of demand | Economics Online”. 2020-01-14. Retrieved 2021-04-14.
2. ^ Browning, Edgar K. (1992). Microeconomic theory and applications. New York City: HarperCollins. pp. 94–95. ISBN 9780673521422.
3. ^ Jump up to:a b Png, Ivan
(1989). p. 57.
4. ^ Parkin; Powell; Matthews (2002). pp. 74–5.
5. ^ Jump up to:a b Gillespie, Andrew (2007). p. 43.
6. ^ Jump up to:a b Gwartney, Yaw Bugyei-Kyei.James D.; Stroup, Richard L.; Sobel, Russell S. (2008). p. 425.
7. ^ Gillespie,
Andrew (2007). p. 57.
8. ^ Ruffin; Gregory (1988). p. 524.
9. ^ Ferguson, C.E. (1972). p. 106.
10. ^ Ruffin; Gregory (1988). p. 520
11. ^ McConnell; Brue (1990). p. 436.
12. ^ Economics, Tenth edition, John Sloman
13. ^ Jump up to:a b
Parkin; Powell; Matthews (2002). p .75.
14. ^ McConnell; Brue (1990). p. 437
15. ^ Jump up to:a b Ruffin; Gregory (1988). pp. 518–519.
16. ^ Jump up to:a b Ferguson, C.E. (1972). pp. 100–101.
17. ^ Jump up to:a b Wall, Stuart; Griffiths, Alan
(2008). pp. 53–54.
18. ^ Jump up to:a b McConnell;Brue (1990). pp. 434–435.
19. ^ Ferguson, C.E. (1972). p. 101n.
20. ^ Sloman, John (2006). p. 55.
21. ^ Wessels, Walter J. (2000). p. 296.
22. ^ Mas-Colell; Winston; Green (1995).
23. ^
Taylor, John (2006). p. 93.
24. ^ Marshall, Alfred (1890). III.IV.2.
25. ^ Marshall, Alfred (1890). III.IV.1.
26. ^ Schumpeter, Joseph Alois; Schumpeter, Elizabeth Boody (1994). p. 959.
27. ^ Negbennebor (2001).
28. ^ Jump up to:a b c d
Parkin; Powell; Matthews (2002). pp. 77–9.
29. ^ Jump up to:a b c d e Walbert, Mark. “Tutorial 4a”. Retrieved 27 February 2010.
30. ^ Jump up to:a b Goodwin, Nelson, Ackerman, & Weisskopf (2009).
31. ^ Jump up to:a b Frank (2008) 118.
32. ^
Jump up to:a b Gillespie, Andrew (2007). p. 48.
33. ^ Jump up to:a b Frank (2008) 119.
34. ^ Jump up to:a b Png, Ivan (1999). pp. 62–3.
35. ^ Reed, Jacob (2016-05-26). “AP Microeconomics Review: Elasticity Coefficients”. APEconReview.com. Retrieved
2016-05-27.
36. ^ Krugman, Wells (2009). p. 151.
37. ^ Goodwin, Nelson, Ackerman & Weisskopf (2009). p. 122.
38. ^ Gillespie, Andrew (2002). p. 51.
39. ^ Jump up to:a b Arnold, Roger (2008). p. 385.
40. ^ Jump up to:a b Wall, Stuart; Griffiths,
Alan (2008). pp. 57–58.
41. ^ “Pricing Tests and Price Elasticity for one product”. Archived from the original on 2012-11-13. Retrieved 2013-03-03.
42. ^ “Pricing Tests and Price Elasticity for several products”. Archived from the original on
2012-11-13. Retrieved 2013-03-03.
43. ^ Samia Rekhi (16 May 2016). “Empirical Estimation of Demand: Top 10 Techniques”. economicsdiscussion.net. Retrieved 11 December 2020.
44. ^ Png, Ivan (1999). pp. 79–80.
45. ^ Sabatelli, Lorenzo (2016-03-21).
“Relationship between the Uncompensated Price Elasticity and the Income Elasticity of Demand under Conditions of Additive Preferences”. PLOS ONE. 11 (3): e0151390. arXiv:1602.08644. Bibcode:2016PLoSO..1151390S. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0151390. ISSN
1932-6203. PMC 4801373. PMID 26999511.
46. ^ “Constant Elasticity Demand and Supply Curves (Q=A*P^c)”. Archived from the original on 13 January 2011. Retrieved 26 April 2010.
47. ^ Perloff, J. (2008). p. 97.
48. ^ Chaloupka, Frank J.; Grossman,
Michael; Saffer, Henry (2002); Hogarty and Elzinga (1972) cited by Douglas (1993).
49. ^ Pindyck; Rubinfeld (2001). p. 381.; Steven Morrison in Duetsch (1993), p. 231.
50. ^ Richard T. Rogers in Duetsch (1993), p. 6.
51. ^ Havranek, Tomas; Irsova,
Zuzana; Janda, Karel (2012). “Demand for gasoline is more price-inelastic than commonly thought” (PDF). Energy Economics. 34: 201–207. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2011.09.003. S2CID 55215422.
52. ^ Algunaibet, Ibrahim; Matar, Walid (2018). “The responsiveness
of fuel demand to gasoline price change in passenger transport: a case study of Saudi Arabia”. Energy Efficiency. 11 (6): 1341–1358. doi:10.1007/s12053-018-9628-6. S2CID 157328882.
53. ^ Jump up to:a b c Samuelson; Nordhaus (2001).
54. ^ Heilbrun
and Gray (1993, p. 94) cited in Vogel (2001)
55. ^ Goldman and Grossman (1978) cited in Feldstein (1999), p. 99
56. ^ de Rassenfosse, Gaétan; van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, Bruno (2007). “Per un pugno di dollari: A first look at the price elasticity
of patents”. Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 23. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1743840. S2CID 219337939.
57. ^ Perloff, J. (2008).
58. ^ de Rassenfosse, Gaétan (2020). “On the price elasticity of demand for trademarks”. Industry and Innovation. 27 (1–2):
11–24. doi:10.1080/13662716.2019.1591939.
59. ^ Goodwin; Nelson; Ackerman; Weisskopf (2009). p. 124.
60. ^ Lehner, S.; Peer, S. (2019), The price elasticity of parking: A meta-analysis, Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, Volume
121, March 2019, pages 177−191″ web|url=https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tra.2019.01.014
61. ^ Davis, A.; Nichols, M. (2013), The Price Elasticity of Marijuana Demand”
62. ^ Brownell, Kelly D.; Farley, Thomas; Willett, Walter C. et al. (2009).
63. ^
Jump up to:a b Ayers; Collinge (2003). p. 120.
64. ^ Jump up to:a b Barnett and Crandall in Duetsch (1993), p. 147
65. ^ “Valuing the Effect of Regulation on New Services in Telecommunications” (PDF). Jerry A. Hausman. Retrieved 29 September 2016.
66. ^
“Price and Income Elasticity of Demand for Broadband Subscriptions: A Cross-Sectional Model of OECD Countries” (PDF). SPC Network. Retrieved 29 September 2016.
67. ^ Krugman and Wells (2009) p. 147.
68. ^ “Profile of The Canadian Egg Industry”.
Agriculture and Agri-Food Canada. Archived from the original on 8 July 2011. Retrieved 9 September 2010.
69. ^ Cleasby, R. C. G.; Ortmann, G. F. (1991). “Demand Analysis of Eggs in South Africa”. Agrekon. 30 (1): 34–36. doi:10.1080/03031853.1991.9524200.
70. ^
Havranek, Tomas; Irsova, Zuzana; Zeynalova, Olesia (2018). “Tuition Fees and University Enrolment: A Meta‐Regression Analysis”. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics. 80 (6): 1145–1184. doi:10.1111/obes.12240. S2CID 158193395.
2. Arnold, Roger
A. (17 December 2008). Economics. Cengage Learning. ISBN 978-0-324-59542-0. Retrieved 28 February 2010.
3. Ayers; Collinge (2003). Microeconomics. Pearson. ISBN 978-0-536-53313-5.
4. Brownell, Kelly D.; Farley, Thomas; Willett, Walter C.; Popkin,
Barry M.; Chaloupka, Frank J.; Thompson, Joseph W.; Ludwig, David S. (15 October 2009). “The Public Health and Economic Benefits of Taxing Sugar-Sweetened Beverages”. New England Journal of Medicine. 361 (16): 1599–1605. doi:10.1056/NEJMhpr0905723.
PMC 3140416. PMID 19759377.
5. Browning, Edgar K.; Browning, Jacquelene M. (1992). Microeconomic Theory and Applications (4th ed.). HarperCollins. Retrieved 11 December 2020.
6. Case, Karl; Fair, Ray (1999). Principles of Economics (5th ed.).
Prentice-Hall. ISBN 978-0-13-961905-2.
7. Chaloupka, Frank J.; Grossman, Michael; Saffer, Henry (2002). “The effects of price on alcohol consumption and alcohol-related problems”. Alcohol Research and Health. 26 (1): 22–34. PMC 6683806. PMID 12154648.
8. Duetsch,
Larry L. (1993). Industry Studies. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. ISBN 978-0-585-01979-6.
9. Feldstein, Paul J. (1999). Health Care Economics (5th ed.). Albany, NY: Delmar Publishers. ISBN 978-0-7668-0699-3.
10. Ferguson, Charles E. (1972).
Microeconomic Theory (3rd ed.). Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin. ISBN 978-0-256-02157-8.
11. Frank, Robert (2008). Microeconomics and Behavior (7th ed.). McGraw-Hill. ISBN 978-0-07-126349-8.
12. Gillespie, Andrew (1 March 2007). Foundations
of Economics. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-929637-8. Retrieved 28 February 2010.
13. Goodwin; Nelson; Ackerman; Weisskopf (2009). Microeconomics in Context (2nd ed.). Sharpe. ISBN 978-0-618-34599-1.
14. Gwartney, James D.; Stroup, Richard
L.; Sobel, Russell S.; David MacPherson (14 January 2008). Economics: Private and Public Choice. Cengage Learning. ISBN 978-0-324-58018-1. Retrieved 28 February 2010.
15. Krugman; Wells (2009). Microeconomics (2nd ed.). Worth. ISBN 978-0-7167-7159-3.
16. Landers
(February 2008). Estimates of the Price Elasticity of Demand for Casino Gaming and the Potential Effects of Casino Tax Hikes.
17. Marshall, Alfred (1920). Principles of Economics. Library of Economics and Liberty. ISBN 978-0-256-01547-8. Retrieved
5 March 2010.
18. Mas-Colell, Andreu; Winston, Michael D.; Green, Jerry R. (1995). Microeconomic Theory. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-1-4288-7151-9.
19. McConnell, Campbell R.; Brue, Stanley L. (1990). Economics: Principles, Problems,
and Policies (11th ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill. ISBN 978-0-07-044967-1.
20. Negbennebor (2001). “The Freedom to Choose”. Microeconomics. ISBN 978-1-56226-485-7.
21. Parkin, Michael; Powell, Melanie; Matthews, Kent (2002). Economics. Harlow: Addison-Wesley.
ISBN 978-0-273-65813-9.
22. Perloff, J. (2008). Microeconomic Theory & Applications with Calculus. Pearson. ISBN 978-0-321-27794-7.
23. Pindyck; Rubinfeld (2001). Microeconomics (5th ed.). Prentice-Hall. ISBN 978-1-4058-9340-4.
24. Png, Ivan
(1999). Managerial Economics. Blackwell. ISBN 978-0-631-22516-4. Retrieved 28 February 2010.
25. Ruffin, Roy J.; Gregory, Paul R. (1988). Principles of Economics (3rd ed.). Glenview, Illinois: Scott, Foresman. ISBN 978-0-673-18871-7.
26. Samuelson;
Nordhaus (2001). Microeconomics (17th ed.). McGraw-Hill. ISBN 978-0-07-057953-8.
27. Schumpeter, Joseph Alois; Schumpeter, Elizabeth Boody (1994). History of economic analysis (12th ed.). Routledge. ISBN 978-0-415-10888-1. Retrieved 5 March 2010.
28. Sloman,
John (2006). Economics. Financial Times Prentice Hall. ISBN 978-0-273-70512-3. Retrieved 5 March 2010.
29. Taylor, John B. (1 February 2006). Economics. Cengage Learning. ISBN 978-0-618-64085-0. Retrieved 5 March 2010.
30. Vogel, Harold (2001).
Entertainment Industry Economics (5th ed.). Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-79264-6.
31. Wall, Stuart; Griffiths, Alan (2008). Economics for Business and Management. Financial Times Prentice Hall. ISBN 978-0-273-71367-8. Retrieved 6 March
2010.
32. Wessels, Walter J. (1 September 2000). Economics. Barron’s Educational Series. ISBN 978-0-7641-1274-4. Retrieved 28 February 2010.
Photo credit: https://www.flickr.com/photos/walkadog/3292434691/’]